Voir la notice de l'article provenant de la source Math-Net.Ru
@article{CGTM_2022_15_a18, author = {Daria Teplova and Egor Ianovski}, title = {Comparing the manipulability of approval voting and borda}, journal = {Contributions to game theory and management}, pages = {236--249}, publisher = {mathdoc}, volume = {15}, year = {2022}, language = {en}, url = {http://geodesic.mathdoc.fr/item/CGTM_2022_15_a18/} }
Daria Teplova; Egor Ianovski. Comparing the manipulability of approval voting and borda. Contributions to game theory and management, Tome 15 (2022), pp. 236-249. http://geodesic.mathdoc.fr/item/CGTM_2022_15_a18/
[1] Aleskerov, F. and Kurbanov, E., “Degree of manipulability of social choice procedures”, Current trends in economics, 8, eds. Alkan A., Aliprantis, C. D. and Yannelis, N. C., Springer, Berlin–Heidelberg, 1999, 595–609
[2] Arribillaga, R. P. and Massó, J., “Comparing generalized median voter schemes according to their manipulability”, Theoretical Economics, 11:2 (2016), 547–586 | DOI | MR | Zbl
[3] Arribillaga, R. P. and Massó, J., “Comparing Voting by Committees According to Their Manipulability”, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 9:4 (2017), 74–107 | DOI
[4] Barberà, S., Sonnenschein, H. and Zhou, L., “Voting by Committees”, Econometrica, 59:3 (1991), 595–609 | DOI | MR | Zbl
[5] Bartholdi, J. J, Tovey, C. A. and Trick, M. A., “The computational difficulty of manipulating an election”, Social choice and Welfare, 6:3 (1989), 227–241 | DOI | MR | Zbl
[6] Bonkoungou, S. and Nesterov, A., “Comparing school choice and college admissions mechanisms by their strategic accessibility”, Theoretical Economics, 16:3 (2021), 881–909 | DOI | MR | Zbl
[7] Conitzer, V., Sandholm, T. and Lang, J., When are elections with few candidates hard to manipulate?, Journal of the ACM, 54:3 (2007), 14–es | DOI | MR
[8] Decerf, B. and Van der Linden, M., “Manipulability in school choice”, Journal of Economic Theory, 197 (2021) | DOI | MR | Zbl
[9] Dummett, M. and Farquharson, R., “Stability in Voting”, Econometrica, 29:1 (1961), 33–43 | DOI | MR | Zbl
[10] Elkind, E., Lackner, M. and Peters, D., “Structured Preferences”, Trends in Computational Social Choice, ed. Endriss, U., 2017, 187–207 | MR
[11] Faliszewski, P., Hemaspaandra, E., Hemaspaandra, L. A. and Rothe, J., “The shield that never was: Societies with single-peaked preferences are more open to manipulation and control”, Information and Computation, 209:2 (2011), 89–107 | DOI | MR | Zbl
[12] Gibbard, A., “Manipulation of Voting Schemes: A General Result”, Econometrica, 41:4 (1973), 587–601 | DOI | MR | Zbl
[13] Kelly, J. S., “Almost all social choice rules are highly manipulable, but a few aren't”, Social choice and Welfare, 10:2 (1993), 161–175 | DOI | MR | Zbl
[14] Moulin, H., “On Strategy-Proofness and Single Peakedness”, Public Choice, 35:4 (1980), 437–455 | DOI
[15] Nitzanà, S., “The vulnerability of point-voting schemes to preference variation and strategic manipulation”, Public Choice, 47:2 (1985), 349–370 | DOI
[16] Pathak, P. A. and Sönmez, T., “School admissions reform in Chicago and England: Comparing mechanisms by their vulnerability to manipulation”, American Economic Review, 103:1 (2013), 80–106 | DOI
[17] Satterthwaite, M. A., “Strategy-proofness and Arrow's conditions: Existence and correspondence theorems for voting procedures and social welfare functions”, Journal of Economic Theory, 10:2 (1975), 187–217 | DOI | MR | Zbl
[18] Walsh, T., Is computational complexity a barrier to manipulation?, Annals of Mathematics and Artificial Intelligence, 62:1–2 (2011), 7–26 | DOI | MR | Zbl